"Post-retirement Financial Strategies: Forecasts and Valuation", European Financial Management, Vol. 18, No. 3, 2012, pp. 324-351.
A pre-publication version is available here.
In the paper I tried to succinctly and somewhat formally summarize the approach to asset pricing that I and my coauthors Jason Scott and John Watson took in our earlier publications, that I have taken in my subsequent research and that I have used for the present value calculations in the RIS software. Here I'll use portions of the EFMA paper with added comments to provide a semi-formal description.
Warning: some of this will be technical. Feel free to skim or ignore it, as needed.
Here goes.
------------
Building on the approach of [Arrow 1952] and [Debreu 1959], I consider first a one- period setting in which there are n possible states of the world. Assume that securities are priced based on their payoffs in the states of the world, using a set of state prices, where ps is the price today of $1 if and only if state s occurs at the end of the period. If the probability of state s is πs, define the pricing kernel value for state s at time t as mst≡ pst/πst, a value that I called in [Sharpe, 2007] the price per chance (PPC). The set of n values of mst is the pricing kernel for time t. To say that only the market portfolio is priced in a single period is to assert that all states with the same market return have the same price per chance. Moreover, societal risk-aversion implies that the higher a state’s market return, the lower should be its price per chance. More fundamentally, if markets are to clear, prices must adjust so that income in a state of scarcity (low market return) costs more than income in a state of plenty (high market return).
-------------
The references are as follows:
--------------
Arrow, Kenneth J., 1952, “Le Role de valeurs boursiers pour la repartition le meillure des risques,” Econometrie, Colloques Internationaux du Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique 11, pp. 41-47.
Debreu, Gerard, 1959, The Theory of Value, Wiley and Sons, New York.
There are two major approaches to asset pricing in Financial Economics. One, starting with the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), builds on the mean/variance portfolio theory of Harry Markowitz. The other, using Pricing Kernels, builds on the state/preference theory developed by Kenneth Arrow and Gerard Debreu. It may surprise some that I favor the latter for applications such the analysis of retirement income strategies; after all, I was awarded a Nobel Prize in Economics for my work on the CAPM. But over the years I have found the state/preference approach better suited to the task of modeling the determination of asset prices in a one-period setting and even moreso in settings involving many periods, as with retirement income analysis.
I labored long and hard to justify this preference in a series of lectures given at Princeton and the subsequent 2007 book referenced above. However, the focus of the book was on a traditional one-period setting in which investment is made at the present time based on estimates of the probabilities of various returns over a single period such as a year. As I showed there, those who have been brought up on the CAPM need not fear obsolescence, since its major qualitative conclusions hold in the state/preference setting. The market portfolio is still an efficient investment for the average investor. Moreover, security and portfolio expected returns are linearly related to a measure of return sensitivity to the returns on the market. There is of course a difference. In the CAPM the appropriate measure (beta) is based on the covariance of a security or portfolio's return with that of the market portfolio. In the Pricing Kernel version, the measure is based on the covariance of a security or portfolio's return with a function of the return on the market portfolio, a result that I called its kernel beta. But the main qualitative message holds in both approaches: securities and portfolios are priced so that higher expected returns are associated with greater probabilities of doing badly in bad times.
The CAPM can be considered a special case of the more general pricing kernel approach in which the kernel for a single investment period is a linear function of the return on the market portfolio over that period. In the book I argued that it is much more plausible to assume that the relationship is non-linear, with a positive price for every possible future state of the world.
The case for such a relationship is far stronger when one attempts to model the determination of asset prices in a multi-period world -- a necessity for analysis of retirement income strategies. This requires some assumption about the efficiency of alternative strategies for investors with different horizons. Moreover, the assumption must be consistent with market clearing -- that is, the collective demands for available securities must equal the supplies. To return to the EFMA paper:
------------
Consistent with the focus on strategies that utilize only the market portfolio and a riskless asset, I assume that only market returns are priced, both in any single period and also for any multi-period horizon. This could be consistent with a model of multi-period equilibrium in the capital markets, although I have no aspirations to develop one here (or elsewhere). In any event, as I will show, the assumption greatly restricts the characteristics of the pricing function.
------------
This may be far too simple a characterization of equilibrium in capital markets. But to value different combinations of income over future years one must make some assumptions and to be credible they should be consistent with market clearing. The approach taken in the EFMA paper seems reasonable. And some such model is better than none. Interestingly, in a world of this sort, it is quite simple to determine the manner in which assets should be priced. Here is the formal analysis from the paper:
------------
Now, consider a two-period case. Letting mt and rt represent vectors of pricing kernel
values and market total returns (value-relatives) respectively for time t, the pricing kernels for periods 1 and 2 can be written as: The references are as follows:
--------------
Arrow, Kenneth J., 1952, “Le Role de valeurs boursiers pour la repartition le meillure des risques,” Econometrie, Colloques Internationaux du Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique 11, pp. 41-47.
Debreu, Gerard, 1959, The Theory of Value, Wiley and Sons, New York.
Sharpe, William F., 2007, Investors and Markets: Portfolio Choices, Asset Prices
and Investment Advice, Princeton University Press, 2007.
---------------
---------------
There are two major approaches to asset pricing in Financial Economics. One, starting with the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), builds on the mean/variance portfolio theory of Harry Markowitz. The other, using Pricing Kernels, builds on the state/preference theory developed by Kenneth Arrow and Gerard Debreu. It may surprise some that I favor the latter for applications such the analysis of retirement income strategies; after all, I was awarded a Nobel Prize in Economics for my work on the CAPM. But over the years I have found the state/preference approach better suited to the task of modeling the determination of asset prices in a one-period setting and even moreso in settings involving many periods, as with retirement income analysis.
I labored long and hard to justify this preference in a series of lectures given at Princeton and the subsequent 2007 book referenced above. However, the focus of the book was on a traditional one-period setting in which investment is made at the present time based on estimates of the probabilities of various returns over a single period such as a year. As I showed there, those who have been brought up on the CAPM need not fear obsolescence, since its major qualitative conclusions hold in the state/preference setting. The market portfolio is still an efficient investment for the average investor. Moreover, security and portfolio expected returns are linearly related to a measure of return sensitivity to the returns on the market. There is of course a difference. In the CAPM the appropriate measure (beta) is based on the covariance of a security or portfolio's return with that of the market portfolio. In the Pricing Kernel version, the measure is based on the covariance of a security or portfolio's return with a function of the return on the market portfolio, a result that I called its kernel beta. But the main qualitative message holds in both approaches: securities and portfolios are priced so that higher expected returns are associated with greater probabilities of doing badly in bad times.
The CAPM can be considered a special case of the more general pricing kernel approach in which the kernel for a single investment period is a linear function of the return on the market portfolio over that period. In the book I argued that it is much more plausible to assume that the relationship is non-linear, with a positive price for every possible future state of the world.
The case for such a relationship is far stronger when one attempts to model the determination of asset prices in a multi-period world -- a necessity for analysis of retirement income strategies. This requires some assumption about the efficiency of alternative strategies for investors with different horizons. Moreover, the assumption must be consistent with market clearing -- that is, the collective demands for available securities must equal the supplies. To return to the EFMA paper:
------------
Consistent with the focus on strategies that utilize only the market portfolio and a riskless asset, I assume that only market returns are priced, both in any single period and also for any multi-period horizon. This could be consistent with a model of multi-period equilibrium in the capital markets, although I have no aspirations to develop one here (or elsewhere). In any event, as I will show, the assumption greatly restricts the characteristics of the pricing function.
------------
This may be far too simple a characterization of equilibrium in capital markets. But to value different combinations of income over future years one must make some assumptions and to be credible they should be consistent with market clearing. The approach taken in the EFMA paper seems reasonable. And some such model is better than none. Interestingly, in a world of this sort, it is quite simple to determine the manner in which assets should be priced. Here is the formal analysis from the paper:
------------
m1 = f1(r1 )
m2 = f2(r2)
The pricing kernel for a horizon that includes both periods 1 and 2 will be the (dot) product of the two kernels. Thus:
m1⋅ m2 = f1(r1 )⋅ f2(r2)
In order for (1) the market to be priced in the same manner for each period and (2) for
only the market to be priced for any multi-year horizon, it must be the case that:
f(r1 ) ⋅ f(r2) = g(r1⋅ r2)
A necessary and sufficient condition for this to be the case is that the one-period pricing function be isoelastic:
mt = Art-b
More generally, if Mt represents the pricing kernel for payments t periods hence and Vt the cumulative market return over that horizon:
Mt = At Vt -b
------------
While this may look formidable, it is quite sensible. Back to the paper:
------------
Taking the logarithms of both sides of the equation:
log(Mt ) = log(At ) − b⋅log(Vt )
Clearly, the b coefficient indicates the elasticity of the pricing kernel with respect to
cumulative market return – for every one percent increase in the latter, the pricing kernel
decreases by approximately b percent. As is well known, this can be interpreted as
indicating that a “representative investor” who holds the market portfolio has a utility
function with a constant relative risk-aversion coefficient of b (for a further discussion, see Sharpe, 2007).
------------
f(r1 ) ⋅ f(r2) = g(r1⋅ r2)
A necessary and sufficient condition for this to be the case is that the one-period pricing function be isoelastic:
mt = Art-b
More generally, if Mt represents the pricing kernel for payments t periods hence and Vt the cumulative market return over that horizon:
Mt = At Vt -b
------------
While this may look formidable, it is quite sensible. Back to the paper:
------------
Taking the logarithms of both sides of the equation:
log(Mt ) = log(At ) − b⋅log(Vt )
------------
The relationship is log-linear. Among other things, this means that every state price is positive, no matter how large or small the return on the market portfolio. This is not the case if the kernel is linear, which can be if one assumes that all investors have quadratic utility functions (and hence care only about the mean and variance of portfolio returns).
This is not the place to pick a fight between proponents of traditional mean/variance portfolio theory with a strict interpretation of the of the CAPM and those (including me) who prefer the state/preference pricing kernel approach. The key point is that we now have a pricing kernel with desirable properties that could be consistent with a multi-period equilibrium. For any period in the future, we can use it to determine the price per chance (PPC) for $1 to be received at that future time if and only if the state occurs. PPC is a function of the cumulative compounded return on the market portfolio from the present to that future time and the function is of the form shown above. And clearly, the price for $1 to be received at a future time and in a given state is equal to the PPC times the chance that the state will occur at the time in question.
To return to the paper:
------------
I will use the pricing kernel primarily to estimate the values of the distributions of spending (also called “payments” or “paychecks”) provided by a strategy. This requires a set of state prices – each of which represents the cost today of obtaining $1 at a given future time and state. Since the pricing kernel is simply a set of ratios of state prices to state probabilities:
Pt = Mt⋅∏t
Where Pt is a vector of state prices for payments at a future time t, and Mt and ∏t are, respectively, vectors for the pricing kernel and probabilities of the states for that time. In the simulations ... market returns were drawn randomly from the underlying probability distributions for n multi-year scenarios. Considering each scenario as a state, the probabilities all equal 1/n so that:
Pt = Mt /n
----------
But how to determine the key parameters in the equation (A and b)? In the simulations for the EFMA paper, I ran a million simulations for each year for every strategy analyzed. Moreover, my Matlab program made it possible to run all the results for each year at one time, then find the pricing kernel that best fit the resulting million simulated compound market returns. For each future year, I found values for the two variables (A and b) that would be consistent with valuations of the market portfolio and the riskless asset for that horizon. As I indicated in a footnote in the paper:
------------
In the simulations ... to reduce sampling errors of draws from the underlying return distribution, the values of A and b used for each horizon were found iteratively based on the requirement that the implied present values of both the cumulative market returns and the cumulative risk-free return were both within a very small distance from 1.0.
------------
John Watson is currently doing research on the efficacy of this and other possible approaches to valuation when using a simulated sample to approximate the universe of all possible scenarios. This procedure produces pricing kernels that may fit the simulated scenarios but may violate the underlying assumption about the multi-period equilibrium. I shall have more to say about this in subsequent posts. But the discussion is not particularly germane for those using the RIS software for two reasons. First, it is infeasible to run a million scenarios. And second, since the software generates results a scenario at a time, this fitting procedure is not feasible since it would require storing at least 40 or 50 million results (a matrix with a row for each scenario and a column for each year).
Fortunately, there is another way, using a formula derived by John Watson in our earlier paper:
Scott, Jason S. with William F. Sharpe and John G. Watson, 2009, "The 4% Rule -- At
What Price?", Journal of Investment Management, Vol. 7, No. 3, Third Quarter 2009, pp.
31-48
It is available here.
As derived in the paper, for the special case in which the return on the market portfolio is assumed to be lognormally distributed in each period (year), the coefficients of the asset pricing equation can be calculated directly. Here is the EFMA paper's description:
-----------
The values of the coefficients in the pricing equation can be computed directly from the parameters of the assumed distributions of annual returns as follows:
In the above equations, Rf is the total risk-free return, Em = E[Rt] is the yearly expected
total market return, and Sm = (Var[Rt])1/2 is the annual market volatility.
------------The RIS software uses these formulas to compute the parameters for the pricing kernel (computing b first, then A). While producing multiple scenarios, the formula is used to compute the state price for each income and fee payment, obtain the resulting present value and update the appropriate cumulative sum.
Unfortunately, with feasible numbers of scenarios the results will be imperfect since the sample scenarios will not be fully representative of the universe of possible future scenarios. As indicated in the previous post, this is reflected in the design of the RIS software. First, present values are shown only when 5,000 or more scenarios have been analyzed. Second, the computed values are not shown, only the percentages of the total value associated with the prospects for three recipients (the household, the estate and those who receive fees). Third, the actual percentages are not shown, only a pie chart indicating their magnitudes. And finally, the user is encouraged to generate additional sets of multiple scenarios to determine the variation in the allocation of the present values from case to case.
Enough caveats. Despite these limitations, the breakdown of present values in the RIS software should provide valuable information in most cases. And some of the analyses that I will describe in subsequent posts will be obtained using Matlab software, employing large numbers of scenarios and, in some cases using different and hopefully more accurate approximations of present values.
I will have much to say about the present values of future possible outcomes in the future analyses of alternative retirement income strategies. You should expect nothing less from an economist.
I have been wondering about retirement income analysis and what I need to know to keep financially secure. This article was informative and helpful! There was a lot of information and I feel like I learned a lot.
ReplyDeleteJessie | http://www.nemethfinancialgroup.com/info.php
Doctor, in my opinion the PPC within the RIS seems to be a way to crash test the traditional 4% rule applied to post retirement income calculations. As a financial adviser in the retirement income market your papers indicate more attention and care needs to be taken when using any projected returns for an individual or family post retirement and retirement red zone assumptions.
ReplyDeleteThank you for the continued contribution. Jim Hughes
Doctor, been studying the pricing kernel methodology. One outcome that's come up is a economic/financial anomaly.
ReplyDeleteCoincidental when reviewing came across "Investopedia explains 'Anomaly'
Anomalies often occur with respect to asset pricing models, in particular the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). Although the CAPM was derived by using innovative assumptions and theories, it often does a poor job in predicting stock returns. The numerous market anomalies that were observed after the formation of the CAPM helped form the basis for those wishing to disprove the model. Although the model may not hold up in empirical and practical tests, that is not to say that the model does not hold some utility.
What about the social impact of 10,000 people either close to entering their retirement years a day over the next 18 years. (http://www.pewresearch.org/daily-number/baby-boomers-retire/)
Couldn't this cause a financial/economic Anomalies in the state/preference approach and what would happen then?
Thank you,
Jim Hughes
I really want to start planning my retirement. I know that it is many years away, but I want to make sure that I am ready when the time comes. I am going to talk to my financial adviser about it. He will be able to help me plan for retirement. http://www.sommerkampfinancial.com
ReplyDeletePainters Cape Town-Looking for professional residential Painters or painting contractors in Cape Town? We are no #1 resource Visit us to hire Painters in Cape Town.
ReplyDeleteLiệu bạn có biết thắc mắc có nên phun thêu lông mày không đã nhận được sự quan tâm từ hang nghìn khách hàng. Địa chỉ làm đẹp phun lông mày ngang hàn quốc Những bí mật ít người biết về thêu chân mày ngang kiểu hàn quốc hay những điều chị em phụ nữ thắc mắc về phun xăm mí mắt bao nhiêu tiền Cho những ai đang có dự định sử dụng dịch vụ làm đẹp thêu lông mày ở đâu đẹp và tự nhiên và phun môi ở đâu đẹp tại hà nội. Có thể bạn chưa biết … hiện đang là dịch vụ hot nhất hiện nay, được nhiều chị em quan tâm.
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by the author.
ReplyDeleteThanks for sharing this wonderful article,
ReplyDeleteEntertainment / Authors / Musicians
It's really an amazing and helpful guide,.
ReplyDeleteOmni Management Corporation
We offers professional training programmes in online marketing for individual and business owners join classroom based and online courses available training digital marketing training
ReplyDeleteThank you for sharing such great information. It is informative, can you help me in finding out more detail on Retirement Plans India , i am interested and would like to know more about this field and wanted to understand the basics of Best Retirement Plans
ReplyDeleteVery good website. I liked it very much.
ReplyDeleteExpress Commission
Real Estate Commission Loans
I will recommend anyone looking for Business loan to Le_Meridian they helped me with Four Million USD loan to startup my Quilting business and it's was fast When obtaining a loan from them it was surprising at how easy they were to work with. They can finance up to the amount of $500,000,000.000 (Five Hundred Million Dollars) in any region of the world as long as there 1.9% ROI can be guaranteed on the projects.The process was fast and secure. It was definitely a positive experience.Avoid scammers on here and contact Le_Meridian Funding Service On. lfdsloans@lemeridianfds.com / lfdsloans@outlook.com. WhatsApp...+ 19893943740. if you looking for business loan.
ReplyDeleteRecording success in Cryptocurrency, Bitcoin is not just buying and holding till when bitcoin sky-rocks, this has been longed abolished by intelligent traders ,mostly now that bitcoin bull is still controlling the market after successfully defended the $40,000 support level once again ad this is likely to trigger a possible move towards $50,000 resistance area However , it's is best advice you find a working strategy by hub/daily signals that works well in other to accumulate and grow a very strong portfolio ahead. I have been trading with Mr Carlos daily signals and strategy, on his platform, and his guidance makes trading less stressful and more profit despite the recent fluctuations. I was able to easily increase my portfolio in just 3weeks of trading with his daily signals, growing my 0.9 BTC to 2.9BTC. Mr Carlos daily signals are very accurate and yields a great positive return on investment. I really enjoy trading with him and I'm still trading with him, He is available to give assistance to anyone who love crypto trading and beginners in bitcoin investment , I would suggest you contact him on WhatsApp: +1(424)285-0682 and telegram : @IEBINARYFX for inquires and profitable trading platform systems. Bitcoin is taking over the world and it’s the best retirement plan
ReplyDeleteThis is a wonderful post, I am very happy to read this article. Cost Advertise on realestate.com.au - A Helpful Illustated guide to Home Owners to advertise your own Home on realestate.com.au by Owner.
ReplyDeleterealty for sale by owner
Thanks for the information you've presented here. I've recommended it to several of my friends as well.
ReplyDeletesell a home yourself websites